CHAPTER 23:
EXPENDITURE MULTIPLIER
Consumption
and Savings Function:
n
Consumption is primarily a function of Yd (disposable income) or
“after-tax” income. Although it is also
influenced by the rate of interest, expectations about future Yd, wealth effects
etc.
n if plot Consumption as a function of Yd it will have a positive vertical intercept (‘autonomous consumption’) and a positive slope but less than one (i.e, the slope of the consumption function is the coefficient on Yd in the Consumption equation and represents the Marginal Propensity to Consume (MPC). Therefore, 0<MPC<1
n if plot the consumption function versus a 45 degree line (with the mathematical property that any point on the 45 degree line has the same vertical coordinate as horizontal coordinate, or x = y) then where Consumption intersects the 45 degree line is referred to as “breakeven level of Yd”.
n at Yd < Yd breakeven, then C > Yd (the individual is ‘dissaving’ as savings <0)
n at Yd > Yd breakeven, then C < Yd and the individual is “saving”, Savings >0.
n the Savings function is derived from the consumption function (if the consumption function changes then so does the savings function). For example, if
C
= a + b (Y
- T) where a>0, 0<b<1 and Yd= Y-T
then the implied savings function is:
S
= - a +
(1-b) (Y - T) where (1-b) =
MPS (marginal propensity to save)
Note: MPC
+ MPS = 1
n
Mathematical example:
if C
= 1000 + 0.80 (Y -T) then the implied savings function
is:
S =
-1000 + 0.20 (Y - T)
where
MPC = 0.80 and MPS = 0.20. See the
graphs pg. 529
Effects
of other variables on Consumption function:
n
if the interest rate falls or expected future disposable income
increases, then the consumption function shifts upwards and the implied savings
function shifts downwards (see pg. 531)
Other
Components of Aggregate Expenditure (AE):
i)
Investment function:
n
depends on interest rate, expected future profits. Not related to
current GDP or Yd. Therefore, if we plot the investment function in diagram
with Investment expenditures on the vertical axis and real GDP on the
horizontal axis, the Investment (I) line is horizontal at I0. That is, we assume that:
I = I0.
ii)
Government expenditures:
n
changes in government expenditures (G) or taxes (T) represents a
“fiscal policy” decision of the federal government. Therefore, a change in G is a policy choice
and does not respond automatically to the level of GDP (Y). So in a diagram, G is also assumed to be
autonomous,
G = G0.
iii) Exports:
n
exports represent Canadian goods sold abroad. The level of exports will depend primarily on
the Canadian price level (P), foreign price level (Pf), the exchange rate (E)
and foreign GDP (Yf). Therefore, once
again, X does not respond to the level of Canadian GDP so exports are
autonomous.
X = X0.
iv) Imports:
n
depends on relative prices (Canadian and foreign prices), the exchange
rate (E), and Canadian GDP (Y). As GDP
(Y) increases, we buy more goods and services and some of these will be
imported from the rest of the world.
Therefore,
Imports (M) = m Y where 0<m<1
and m=MPM (marginal propensity to import)
Aggregate Expenditure
function (AE):
n
will have a positive intercept (see graph pg. 534)
n the slope of the AE function is given by:
n
slope of AE = MPC (1-t) - MPM where 0<t<1
and
t represents the tax rate
n
Note if we have lump sum taxes, T = To ( a constant) then t=0 and the
slope of the AE function is just = MPC - MPM
n
Numerical Example:
If MPC = 0.80, MPM = 0.10 and t =
0.25 then the slope of the AE function is:
slope of AE = 0.80 (1 - 0.25) - 0.10
slope of AE = 0.50
Equilibrium GDP (Y):
n
when AE = Y (planned spending = production) we have an equilibrium
n graphically this occurs anywhere along the 45 degree line with AE on the vertical axis and real GDP (Y) on the horizontal axis. Specifically, the equilibrium is where the given AE function intersects the 45 degree line. (see pg. 536)
Calculation
of Equilibrium GDP (Y):
n
Suppose you are given the following equations:
C
= 1000 + 0.80 (Y- T)
I
= 180
G
= 100
X = 200
M
= 0.20 Y
T
= 100
n
To find equilibrium GDP, follow these steps:
n Step 1: Calculate the AE equation by adding C, I G, X and M together and substitute the T value into the consumption equation
AE =
C + I
+ G +
X - M
so AE = 1000 +
0.80(Y -100) + 180 + 100 + 200 - 0.20 Y
or AE
= 1400 +
0.60 Y
-Step 2:
Impose the equilibrium condition, AE = Y
so 1400 + 0.60
Y =
Y
and since the equilibrium condition
has been imposed, the value of Y solved for is then equilibrium Y.
n
Step 3: Solve for equilibrium GDP
0.40 Y = 1400
so Y = 3500
The Multiplier:
n
the definition of the multiplier is:
multiplier = change
in equilibrium Y
change
in autonomous spending
n
the formula for the expenditure multiplier is: multiplier = 1
1 - slope of AE function
Example: If the MPC = 0.80, t = 0, and MPM = 0.05 then
the
slope of the AE function is = 0.75 and the multiplier is = 4
Therefore,
for everyone $1 increase in spending (whether it be from C, I, G, X) it will
generate a $4 increase in equilibrium GDP.
n
continuing the example from above where equilibrium Y = 3500, if full
employment GDP (Y*) = 4300 then in order to get to full employment GDP the
government could increase its spending by 200 (once subject to the multiplier,
the overall increase in GDP is going to be $800 bringing the new equilibrium
GDP level to $4300 (=Y*)
The Lump sum Tax multiplier:
n
if the government has a lump sum tax (so the tax rate, t = 0),then a $1
increase in taxes would reduce Consumption expenditures by the value of the MPC
(eg 0.80). This reduction in
expenditures is then subject to the multiplier.
The end result is that when taxes (T) change, equilibrium GDP changes
according to the value of the tax multiplier,
n
definition of the tax multiplier: tax
multiplier = - MPC
1 - slope of the AE function
Example:
If
the MPC = 0.80, t = 0 and MPM = 0.05 then the tax multiplier is:
tax multiplier = -0.80
1
- 0.75
then
the tax multiplier is -3.2
The
tax multiplier is always a negative number because from the definition of the
tax multiplier above, we know that if taxes increase (decrease), then real GDP
will decrease (increase) so the tax multiplier is negative.
n
you use the tax multiplier to determine the required change in taxes to
bring about full employment GDP. Suppose
again that Y (eq’l) = 3500 and Y* = 4300 and the tax multiplier is -3.2
then
from the definition of the tax multiplier:
tax
multiplier = change in equilibrium GDP
change in taxes (lump sum)
so
if the tax multiplier is -3.2 and to get to full employment GDP we want the
change in equilibrium GDP to be +$800, then the change in taxes should be =
800/-3.2 or = -$250
The Multiplier and the Price
Level:
n
the price level (P) was held constant in deriving the AE function. Therefore, if the price level changes it will
shift the AE curve (due to the wealth effect and the substitution effects, see
page 543).
n specifically, if the price level increases, AE shifts down (the increase in price reduces real wealth and encourages international and intertemporal substitution so consumption expenditures decrease and imports increase lowering equilibrium GDP). See graphs on page 544.
Derivation of the AD curve:
n
can derive the AD curve (from chapter 22) by changing the price level
and tracing out what happens to equilibrium GDP following the shift in the AE
curve. See page 544.
n we can also trace out the effects of changes in other variables (eg changes in the interest rate or exchange rate etc) on the AD curve itself. See page 545. If the AE curve shifts upwards due to any effect but a change in price, then the AD curve will shift in response. See page 545.
Note: you should read over the Appendix to Chapter 23 (the mathematical note at the end of the chapter).